Capitalist stagnation
U.S.
workers’ wages stagnated in the last three decades, state-driven China almost
alone internationally in substantially improving popular living standards.
While other political economists in Marx’s day had observed a tendency for
profit rates—driving production under capitalism—to decline, Karl Marx claimed the decline is inevitable, this
forming the conclusion of Marx’s three-volume magnum opus, Capital.
Marx’s central
argument is counterintuitive but simple. Value
consists of labor hours embodied in products. Employers (capitalists) profit by paying laborers for their time, the amount
of value paid being less than the amount of socially necessary labor the
workers add. With capitalism’s evolution, a declining proportion of the value produced
is constituted of labor directly employed, an increasing proportion of
labor already concretized in capital goods, since mechanization of production is
the fundamental means to increasing economic efficiency, where capital goods
contribute to the value of a product to the extent they are consumed in its production. With the increasing organic
composition of capital—as proportionately more value is created through
capital goods—rate of profit must fall, since it is based on exploiting labor and that already
embodied in capital goods has been sold and accounted for.
Despite its
centrality to Marx’s analysis of why capitalism eventually comes to retard
economic progress, the tendency of the rate of profit to decline is far from
universally accepted as true even by Marxian commentators. Marxian academics have even questioned it mathematically,
but the real issue isn’t the almost-trivial mathematics but its mapping to
reality: does the declining Marxian
rate of profit entail a declining actual
rate of profit?
Conflicting
reciprocity norms
That owners
of capital (capitalists) profit from
a series of “fair” exchanges could be termed the central premise of Capital. Workers exchange their labor
time for its value—that is, the laborers’ own price of reproduction. The
arrangement is fair under a reciprocity norm according to which commodities
trade at their market value. But it is unfair under a reciprocity norm
according to which all receive in proportion to their value-producing labor. Although
Marx didn’t stress the point, what’s striking is that each antagonist in the historical drama—the social
classes workers and capitalists—frames its interests in
terms of a simple coherent reciprocity principle, with the difference that the
workers favor a ratio derived from production and the capitalists from
distribution. (See Alan Page Fiske, Structures of Social Life: The Four
Elementary Forms of Human Relations (1991) [“equality matching” and “market pricing,”
but Fiske, while discussing Marx, doesn’t link equality matching to the labor
theory of value].)
The market’s function
Attacks on the
soundness of Marx’s law of the tendency of the rate of profit to decline derive
from its seeming impossibility—this, in turn, due to not seeing the connection between “profit” as defined in the theory and in the ledger. We must
start from fundamentals. According to Marx, civil society exists to allow human
cooperation in the labor process. Civilization is built on accomplishing this
by fostering the accumulation of economic resources by few; capitalism was the
form economies came to take at the onset of the industrial revolution. Like
other economic systems that followed the agricultural revolution, it arose and
became ascendant because of its efficiency in extracting value from labor,
but it accomplishes this with a progressive enlargement of the value diverted
to augmenting industrial machinery rather than directly producing more products
for consumption, which gradually changes the tasks presented. As the contribution
of machinery grows relative to the direct contribution of laborers, the basic
economic tasks besetting society change from producing value from labor to
realizing the value embodied in machinery.
But the
capitalist market continues to be a system adapted to extracting value from
labor. Insofar as profit represents a gain in value accruing to the capitalist
class as a whole, it comes from the
value contributed by the laborers. As the production process has progressively
less proportionate need for laborers, it becomes harder to profit sufficiently
at their expense.
Limits of state action under capitalism
It might be
thought that this Marxian profit is a reification. Who’s to say it is the
proper abstraction for understanding capitalist motivation, rather than, say,
the concept of “interest,” favored by the ultracapitalist “Austrian school.” One
response that denies the centrality of Marxian profit (technically, surplus value) is that state action can
co-opt the market to new ends. Since the market tends to overproduce capital,
adroit government spending might redirect it to produce more consumer goods.
This is the essence of Keynes’s policies. The most obvious problem is that unprofitable spending is competitively
inefficient and is only sustainable in huge nation states with considerable
economic autonomy; otherwise, it may cause a nation’s industries to fail
against international competitors, who are free-riders on the increased buying
power of the local population. International economic competition sets limits
on a country’s ability to use Keynesian policies or any policies involving
state subsidy. Yet periods aren’t rare when one capitalist power dominates and
is subject to diminished international competition. Also, if Keynesian policies
are directed to creating positive externalities or “public goods” favoring
profitability, their benefit may outweigh their harm to profits.
But insuperable
obstacles to using government to redirect the market keep Marxian surplus value a good first approximation
to balance-sheet profit. While a government-regulated market is often thought
to provide the best of capitalism and socialism, in an important sense, it
provides the worst of each in that the state attempts to regulate in ignorance
of the facts, a company’s plans a closely guarded commercial secret. But the
more fundamental problem with government-directed capitalism is that it amounts
to the government’s adding to some capitalists' profits at the expense of other
capitalists. Where political power follows economic power, the political unity
of the class of capitalists depends on their shared economic interests.
Private property is the means of coordinating individuals into a social class
sufficiently unified to legitimize government. This unity depends on
allocating wealth according to the dominant reciprocity norm, based on market
exchange rates.
The result
is only limited government
intervention can please the capitalist class. Rather than contributing to the
profits of the class, government policy must use incentives which advantage
parts of the class at the expense of the other parts. To create an incentive sufficient to replace
the incentive of Marxian profit with balance-sheet profit, differently
constituted, would involve huge wealth transfers within the capitalist class, calling
the system’s legitimacy into question by undermining its broad support by the dominant
social class.
Corrected on January 2, 2013: the organic composition of capital increases rather than declines. The point is purely terminological and the result of my still not grasping why machinery is termed "organic." Thanks to a correspondent, who corrected me.
Corrected on January 2, 2013: the organic composition of capital increases rather than declines. The point is purely terminological and the result of my still not grasping why machinery is termed "organic." Thanks to a correspondent, who corrected me.
"Since the market tends to overproduce capital, adroit government spending might redirect it to produce more consumer goods. This is the essence of Keynes’s policies"
ReplyDeleteI tend to read Keynes-sympathizers like Daniel Kuehn complain that Austrians misrepresent Keynes as being about consumption, when Keynes actually placed a lot of emphasis on the volatility of investment and wanted the government to ensure that it did not crash in panic periods.
I've never before heard the claim that capital goods are "overproduced" (by what standard?). I have often heard that the Sovet Union underproduced consumer goods, focused on military production. Of course the guns vs butter tradeoff exists in many other countries though.
In the run-up to a recession, there is often an oversupply of capital seeking outlets. This may take the form of investment capital rather than actually produced capital goods. "Overproduction" is relative to what the capitalist market can absorb.
Delete